After WWII, nearly every European country adopted some kind of socialized health care system. There is much to learn from their experiences since then, though one of the most important lessons is that systems are highly dependent on cultural context -- in other words, what works in one country will not necessarily work in another, and what fails in one country may work fine in another.
The first step the US will need to take is to decide what the goals are of the system. The Netherlands papers on health care commonly refer to equity, quality, and efficiency
as the three goals of the Netherlands health care system. Something which delivers one is not acceptable if it compromises the others. It is likely that the US would not adopt these three axes precisely, but they do provide a useful lens with which to view the current US health care system and discuss its shortcomings.
Equity: The US health care system is obviously not equitable. Currently, 18% of Americans are uninsured, many more are underinsured. The quality of coverage/care provided under different insurance plans varies widely, and regulation currently seems to be anti-patient (such as recent laws to prevent a patient from suing their HMO) rather than protective of the patient. Additionally, many care providers refuse to accept Medicare and/or Medicaid patients, resulting in a separate (and probably not equal) set of providers available to patients on these systems.
Quality: It is frequently proclaimed that we have the best health care system on the planet!
However, this simply does not appear to be the case. In terms of measures such as expected life span and infant mortality rate the US measures average or below compared to other first-world countries. The primary mechanism for maintaining quality in the US health care system is the malpractice law suit. However, studies on malpractice litigation consistently show that there is a poor correlation between medical errors that cause harm to the patient and malpractice litigation. The problem goes both ways: most law suits decide in favor of the physician (that whatever harm resulted was simply not the physician's fault), and medical record reviews show that most serious medical errors are never seen in court (see the Harvard Medical Practice Study). Clearly, a different mechanism of ensuring quality is needed.
Efficiency: The one way in which the US health care system is the best
is that we spend the most money on it. Including private and public spending, we spend twice as much as the average first-world country on our health care. Clearly our system is woefully inefficient
Why is this system not working? I think we can divide that analysis into two categories:
There are several assumptions that are made in any free market which are clearly untrue for the health care sector.
How much would you pay to save your life? If your net worth is, say, 1000 MegaBux (and that's your net worth alone - if you're married, probably your spouse has 1000 MB of their own) how much would you pay to save your life? How about both your legs? Your genitals? Your brain? How about your spouse's life? Odds are that most of us would be willing to donate a considerable part of our 1000 MB to save our loved ones. What if you had 100,000 MB?
In health care, market price is more determined by the individual's ability to pay than the value of the product. In fact, most of us would be willing to give up some of our share to help another, or go into debt to save ourselves. This means that the total market value of the health care system is, by this mechanism, greater than the GNP. No wonder we have the most expensive health care system on the planet!
If we *can* pay for a needed health service, we probably will pay it - no matter what the price.
Those of you who drank Friedman's kool aid will be thinking, Yes, but you could say the same thing about water or food.
True, and if you know the history of the water riots in Bolivia and India you can see that this can be a problem. However, in the US, we still have sufficient competition or regulation in these areas to keep prices reasonable. If the price on flour is too high, you can always buy cornmeal. Health care isn't like that. If you need a corneal transplant, a kidney transplant will not do in its place. Drug prices don't come down until the patents expire, and specialist care costs approximately the same no matter who you see to get it.
When's the last time you went to the doctor for something, and he said, Well, we ought to screen you for Dutch Elm Disease. That screening will cost you $80 out of pocket, your insurance will pay $150, unless you have not yet reached your deductible.
Nope, doesn't happen. Doctors (and consequently patients) have no idea what stuff costs nor what your particular insurance will cover.
However, there is a second customer
which *does* know how much stuff costs, but isn't present at the medical consultation. After you have received your care, the insurance company will tell you if the price is one they are willing to pay. If it is not, you are stuck with the bill. This is usually couched as Your care was not provided by one of our Preferred Care Providers.
How do you know if your surgeon is the best or the worst? Furthermore, if your physician recommends a procedure, do you ever ask, Gee, Doc, is there anything that's much cheaper that would be nearly as good?
The first is a VERY sticky problem -- attempts to create accountability
for physicians have generally resulted in witch hunts, bad blood, and bad information rather than any useful information for the patient (see previous post on outcome based
things). The second is not something that the patient is in the position to judge... and perhaps more importantly, neither is the insurance company. Sure, maybe in general Cheaploxx is equally safe and cheaper than Costsaloxx, but maybe it's not so safe if you mess up the dosing schedule, and Costsaloxx is going to be more reliable in the face of old Mrs. Smith's fading memory. We've all heard horror stories of the insurance only being willing to pay for the second best
care. However, the opposite problem occurs too: in the face of the threat of malpractice, doctors will generally prescribe Costsaloxx for every patient, even if it's really no better in the majority of cases.
Attempts to regulate the cost of care by introducing shared costs, such as co-pays and deductibles, DO reduce the number of medical visits, but DO NOT reduce the percentage of unneeded
medical visits. It turns out that people go to the doctor when they feel they need to, not because they think it's fun. Such measures result in a delay of needed care. While I have not seen an economic analysis of the effect, my suspicion is that if you consider the true costs, such a program either breaks even or comes out costing more than simply letting people go to the doctor whenever they feel they need it.
Perverse incentivizing:
The term showed up in a Dutch article on health care systems, and I've grown fond of it. What it basically means is follow the money
: what behaviors are rewarded, which are discouraged? To analyze this thoroughly we'd have to look at each of the many players in the health care system: patients, physicians, hospital departments, hospitals, insurances (and the different kids of insurances: Medicaid, HMO's, etc.), customers of insurances (sometimes individuals but usually businesses), etc. Think about it for a while, but I'll highlight some of the bigger problems.
We've already touched on some of them. Doctors are generally incentivized to CYA, with the exception of HMO's which simply give doctors a list of things they aren't allowed to do, rather than encourage actual cost-consciousness. Patients are incentivized to avoid getting care, and treat themselves with OTC medicines if possible.
Hospitals are generally for-profit. True, they are run by people who probably are compassionate, but what is rewarded is profit. Thus hospitals are incentivized to charge as much as they can until the insurance won't pay any more, then boot you out as quickly as possible. If you don't have insurance, they are incentivized to do the minimum allowable by law and then boot you out... or simply refuse to accept uninsured patients except on emergency, which is what a lot of hospitals do. Patients are then incentivized to only come in on emergency service, creating delays in the emergency room.
Insurance companies are for-profit as well. Thus, the ideal for an insurance company is to charge as high of a premium as possible and never pay anything out. From the market viewpoint the only force that should limit this is the customer's willingness to pay the premium: obviously, if the insurance really pays for *nothing*, no one will buy it. However, anyone who's ended up in the cogs of the insurance machinery lately will likely have observed that the insurance companies seem to try everything they can to weasel out of paying. It's not in our preferred provider plan, you didn't get the service pre-approved, it's a pre-existing condition, that treatment is not covered in your plan: see sub-sub-subsection 113 on page 4223 of your plan. And believe me, the picture isn't any rosier from the viewpoint of a business trying to negotiate insurance coverage for its employees. The prices keep going up every year (they went up 25% in one year I was working for the veterinary hospital) and offering less coverage for the money. Large corporations can often negotiate better deals, which means that you're better off working for a big business than a small one... which is another perversity that I won't discuss here.
The idea behind the market forces
movement here in Europe is to align financial incentives with the values of equity, quality, and efficiency. One expert
even said, If you start paying doctors based on their outcomes, you'll see outcomes improve
(he was wrong, they don't). Aligning the market forces
is a very tricky business, and I'm not convinced it will work... but eliminating market forces
that are working against you is essential.
What can we learn from the European experience? Here are some examples:
Hello, Nurse!The British were having trouble with long waiting times in their emergency rooms. They decided to measure
time until the patient sees a nurse.The hospitals scrambled to comply with the requirements (which were unfortunately bereft of any plan or support for instituting them) and came up with a nurse who would see the patient immediately upon arrival, but not actually help them.
reformslab. Which brings us to:
informal paymentsdeveloped, where specialists began to see patients sooner (usually after-hours) for an additional out-of-pocket fee. This inequity of care is what ultimately brought the system under the knife. Importantly for the US: we can expect the same thing to happen if the case load for all medical services suddenly rises by 18%. We must plan for this effect and take measures to counter it.
least worstof the private insurance, and probably get lousy coverage and lousy service on top of it all.
efficientoverall.
What things are peculiar to the American system?
seat at the table.The real challenge for an American health care plan is to keep this monster from eating everything on the table, the table itself, and several of the other dinner guests.
earnedit. The European value of
equitable caremay simply not float in the US, especially when the health care plan hits some growing pains and the conservatives start pointing fingers at those who benefit from the system more than they pay for it.
Then, at last, the question: what should we do? The first thing any realistic liberal should do is assemble a think tank to think about the problem. Preferably with a few representatives from other country's health care systems, or at least some well traveled Americans. They should spend at least six months learning everything they can about what has gone before (I've spent about six days on it, as part of my current Master's program, but I've barely scratched the surface) and then set to work designing an equitable, effective, efficient, and sustainable health care system. It won't be perfect, but it'll be a hell of a lot better than pretending we have nothing to learn from other countries' successes and mistakes.
Given my six days of information, I'd propose something like this: